Tuesday 14 January 2014

'Well'... the US have done it...


Yesterday, I was suitably unenthused by the declaration that the PM was “going all in” on fracking. His visit to a fracking site around the Lincolnshire town of Gainsborough followed the announcement that French oil giant Total was investing £30 million in two exploratory wells in Lincolnshire. The “going all in” apparently entails financial ‘incentives’ (widely being described as bare-faced bribes) to the tune of allowing local councils who permit fracking to retain 100% of the business rates from the shale development, as well as receiving 1% of the revenues from the respective company. Even if the area is seen as unviable, if the council allows exploration, they will receive £100,000 from the drilling company (Pincher, 2014).

Cameron claims that encouraging fracking could create 74,000 jobs (a figure seemingly plucked from nowhere considering that current explorations are minimal and the industry is just starting out), and could bring in £3 billion in investment and improve energy infrastructure in the country (Johnstone, 2014). And yet, Cameron is claiming his climate commitments remain intact. Well I say they are looking worse for wear. There are some more understandable arguments, such as if shale gas replaced the 23% share that coal contributes to our energy mix, then this would decrease carbon emissions for the 23% share, by 50% (Gross, 2013). However, I feel the likelihood of this either being regulated for or occurring through market forces, is slim due to the decreasing price of US coal.

The process of fracking:

Essentially, once the well is dug (approximately 1-2 miles deep depending on the geology), a solution of water, sand and chemicals – namely acids to dissolve the minerals, gelling agents to suspend the sand, and other substances to aid fracturing of the rock (Gross, 2013), is forced down the well to release the gas.

The perceived dangers:

The (thankfully) widespread opposition to fracking in the UK is based on a few key aspects of perceived effects on the environment and humans. These are mainly: 
  • The risk of earthquakes and tremors
  • Risk of pollution to groundwater and downstream
  • Effect of the wells on the landscape
Earthquakes have featured very prominently in the UK media following the early Cuadrilla earthquakes in Lancashire registering at 1.5 and 2.3 on the Richter scale, not long after the drilling commenced (Gross, 2013). The main problem with the risk of earthquakes is that insufficient research has been conducted in specific areas to ascertain whether this will be an ever-present risk.

Regarding the risk of pollution, this is also dependent on location-specific factors such as geology, however the numerous stories (and now even films) shower the US media with ideas about the effects of pollution, and even when taken with the necessary pinch of salt, do indicate a relatively widespread issue. The groundwater pollution is caused when the boreholes have cracks and the fracking solution reaches an aquifer. This can have ecological effects and effects for domestic water supply – hence the pictures/videos of people seemingly setting their tap water alight in the US due to the hydrogen gas concentration. Environmental effects come in two main categories; huge water demands that fracking bring (i.e. 750,000 – 1.5 million cubic meters per frack (BeebeeJaun, 2013)) and the water pollution which occurs through the wastewater disposal.

The landscape is a key concern, especially in sensitive areas such as around the Lake District where fracking is being explored already. The exploration and possible exploitation of shale gas will exclusively occur in rural regions where the communities are more concerned about their local environment overall.

The US excuse:

The US have done well from it, with a 75% increase in natural gas production between 2004 – 2011; mainly due to the exploitation of shale gas on a massive scale, in some areas of Texas there are up to 12 wells per km2 (Beebeejaun, 2013)! Their energy prices have dropped – leading to the EU importing huge amounts of their coal (very climate conscious… cough). However there are rather a few differences between the US and the UK; population density, known shale gas reserves, and primarily – land area.

Recent announcements:

The encouragement of shale gas exploration and exploitation is seen as premature, as Bamberger and Oswald believe that a complete ban on fracking is required before a full and comprehensive evaluation of the risks and possible resources present in the UK. This is related to the fact that it has been speculated that French company Total have only invested in the UK because France have banned fracking completely, the Netherlands have a temporary ban until more research is conducted (Revell, 2014) and Germany are strongly opposed to it. In regards to the financial incentives for fracking, Sir Cockell (chair of the Local Government Association) responded to the 1% of company revenues to be given back to local councils as a ‘token’, and he asserts this should be increased to 5-10% to be in line with global standards, and this money should be put directly into a community fund (Vaughan, 2014).

Personally, I believe that although gas is a better alternative to coal, this argument is too flawed to be relied upon, as there is no guarantee that it would be coal trade which suffers and not renewables. The point that gas could be used as the transition fuel to a renewable system was made at least 20 years ago, and therefore exploiting another (harder to access and less efficient) form of gas should not be used as an addition to this excuse. The three risks outlined above, although serious if fracking becomes prominent, are secondary to the issue of the delayed movement to a primarily renewable system, and in a similar fashion to my previous post on geoengineering, is distracting from the development and investment in win-win renewable technology.

Thursday 9 January 2014

The A&E climate doctor?

Moving in the opposite direction to a few of my previous posts on the topic of small scale or locally governed renewable projects; geoengineering (GE) has resurfaced in the last few weeks in both popular and academic circles.

Geoengineering mainly consists of two broad categories of technology/methodology:
  1. Carbon Dioxide Removal (CDR) – to prevent the root cause of climate change
  2.  Solar Radiation Management (SRM)  – to offset the effects of climate change

Within these categories;
CDR: increasing carbon sinks, using biomass for sequestration and an energy source, enhancing natural weathering to remove CO2, and the direct uptake of atmospheric and oceanic CO2.
SRM: brightening structures, covering deserts in reflective material, sulphate aerosols and shields/deflectors in space (Royal Society, 2009).

CDR is widely accepted as the better approach of the two as it addresses the problem and the cause of climate change, as opposed to SRM which carries higher uncertainties in regards to indirect and unforeseen effects of reducing the radiation reaching the earth’s surface. The merits of SRM are that they do act immediately and stop a certain amount of radiation reaching the earth’s surface, therefore could be used in times of emergency – although I am critical of the reality of this eventuality. Who will decide the category of ‘emergency’, and how will this be funded as there is currently no international body with a mandate to regulate geoengineering projects (Royal Society, 2009)?

Recently, research was published which caught the media’s attention; as it concluded that using SRM could have huge drought-enhancing effects in tropical regions. The research focussed on using sulphate aerosols (to the equivalent of five Mount Pinatubo eruptions!), and they showed how this affects tropical overturning circulation which controls rainfall. The droughts could be caused by the layer of sulphate aerosols removing the temperature gradient, therefore suppressing convection and reducing precipitation (Ferraro et al.,2014). This would have devastating effects on billions of people, mainly through the effect on agriculture.

The effects wouldn’t be entirely uniform but are expected to affect the tropical areas in S. America, Asia and Africa. However, the benefits of the technology are predicted be felt in the higher latitudes, therefore creating a risk of conflict between the nations who have installed/funded the technology and those who are being negatively affected by it (Carrington,2014). There will need to be an international body created to deal with the issues of geoengineering as currently “changing another country’s weather is even classed as a war crime under the Geneva Convention” (Hogenboom, 2013). The effects of creating GE technology would resonate globally (both positively and negatively), therefore this cannot be implemented unilaterally or bilaterally. However, due to the speed of previous and current climate change negotiations, I cannot see a functioning and fair international agreement being created.

In the UK, ‘SPICE’ was created to trial sulphur particle effects on the atmosphere and was tested in September 2011, and the UK was early to the game of geoengineering, as the US has only recently begun to catch up. The testing has not been done on a large enough scale to affect the global climate; yet (Macnaghten and Owen, 2011), and the UK government’s vague stance on geoengineering simply states that there is insufficient research into the technology thus far.


Personally, I feel some geoengineering methods – those which are more ‘natural’ such as reforestation and increasing other carbon sinks should be encouraged as those often involve simply restoring the environment to a previous state (i.e. before humans got their hands on it). Otherwise, geoengineering in its current state is too under-researched to become viable safely, and the levels of governance required are not present either; and I am doubtful as to whether an international agency could feasibly be created for technologies which could have such varying affects globally. Most importantly, I feel that attention given to geoengineering distracts researchers, investment and governments from the main climate change action which should occur – changing and diversifying the global energy mix to a renewables dominated system.

Friday 27 December 2013

A climate conscious Christmas?

"There’s nothing they need, nothing they don’t own already, nothing they even want. So you buy them a solar-powered waving queen; a belly button brush; a silver-plated ice cream tub holder; a “hilarious” inflatable zimmer frame; a confection of plastic and electronics called Terry the Swearing Turtle; or – and somehow I find this significant – a Scratch Off World wall map.
They seem amusing on the first day of Christmas, daft on the second, embarrassing on the third. By the twelfth they’re in landfill. For thirty seconds of dubious entertainment, or a hedonic stimulus that lasts no longer than a nicotine hit, we commission the use of materials whose impacts will ramify for generations."
--George Monbiot

This quote from George Monbiot from his Guardian article particularly struck me when I was considering my Christmassy blog post over the last few days. Although his attitude towards the Christmas mass consumerism does seem to me to be leaning towards the unnecessarily dour side (i.e. have all the gifts in landfill by the 12th day of Christmas), I can empathise with his wider point. Having had the misfortune of experiencing Oxford Street anywhere near Christmas time, the issue of frantic mass consumerism was apparent to me. According to climate psychologist Rosemary Randall, the average Brit now has a carbon footprint three times larger than the average in the 1950s, and I’m surprised it isn’t more (Randall, 2011).

In several countries, consumerism is being used as a tool to recover from economic stagnation, most significantly being in the Netherlands (Kopnina, 2014). However, what is considered consumerism needs to be analysed, and environmental concerns considered if a movement away from the current paradigm is to occur. There have been many theories proposed in order to change the dominant economic practise, such as ‘ecological modernisation’ (EC), ‘postmaterialist value theory’ (PMVT) and the ‘Environmental Kuznets curve’ (EKC). In turn, these involve:
  • EM: natural resources can be used for growth and development – an anthropocentric view.
  • PMVT: greater wealth leads to greater environmental values.
  • EKC: in early industrialisation materials are used intensely, up to a threshold of development were structural economic changes lead to a lessening in material use.

However, in reality these ideals have barely been considered, as the “material saturation level of ‘developed’ societies is far from sustainable” (Kopnina, 2014). What ideally needs to change is the level AND type of consumerism practised, meaning the pure volume of materials consumed and the increased consideration of the whole production chain.

All of these theories show how the issue of sustainable consumerism is still anthropocentric, which links to the proposition put forth by Crutzen in 2002, that we are living in a new geological epoch of the Anthropocene. He proposes that since 1784 (Watt’s steam engine) that humans have altered the environment so much that we are now the dominant force affecting most of the earth, therefore it warrants a new geological epoch as the earth system is vastly different from previous states. Fundamental in this shift is the use of fossil fuels and non-renewable energies which has vastly contributed to the dominance of humans in the earth system. This is why renewable technology is vital to the economic and cultural change required to prevent further ecological and environmental damage, of which Christmas consumerism is only a part!

Along that theme, a rather large Christmas present given to the Humber region recently, has been the announcement of the government approval of the ABLE Marine Energy Park which will be a huge enterprise area dedicated to the manufacture, assembly and repair of offshore wind turbines to supply the huge plans for wind farms in the North Sea. This will provide around 4000 jobs for the area and ideally act as a catalyst for the whole region to become a renewable energy hub (www.ableuk.com).

This move in the Humber region has been welcomed across the board and hopefully will act as an example both nationally and globally, to encourage the economic shift to a more environmentally conscious system, accompanied by the appropriate cultural change, which over time, could lead to a rather different Christmas!

Monday 16 December 2013

'Renewables Obligation' - the most ironic policy

Recently, the government announcement of the retraction of certain ‘green taxes’ to ‘save consumers money’ has shed light on the confusing nature of the UK’s energy policy with various renewables incentives. Therefore I will do a quick breakdown of the main incentives to increase renewable energy production in the UK (although, it’s set to change, again, in spring 2014).
  • Renewables Obligation (RO)
  • Energy Companies Obligation (ECO)
  • Renewable Heat Incentive (RHI)
  • Feed In Tariffs (FITs)
  • Green Deal

ECO: Comprises three aims; 1) Carbon Emissions Reduction Obligation – helping homes which are harder to retrofit and less able to be funded through the Green Deal, 2) Community Obligation – providing insulation measures for lower income areas, and 3) Home Heating Cost Reduction Obligation – companies must provide measures for low income and vulnerable households which lead to savings.

RHI: This is an incentive for the non-domestic sector and essentially provides a subsidy for renewable heat generators for up to 20 years. In spring 2014, this programme will be extended to encourage domestic renewable heat generation (Ofgem, 2013).

RO: This is meant to encourage large scale RE development. It targets electricity suppliers and requires them to acquire a certain percentage of their power from renewable sources, and the value is set annually and increases per year. Renewable Obligation Certificates are allocated and can be traded and generated, and are shown to the regulator Ofgem to show their renewable capacity. However, in a similar fashion to carbon pricing, these ROCs are criticized for being sold too cheaply, at about £46 per ROC. Market controls are imposed in a way to make sure that a surplus and therefore devaluation of ROCs occur. This is done by creating ‘headroom’ - a margin between supply of ROCs and the level of obligation (demand), which creates the much needed certainty regarding market demand.

FITs: these financial incentives are aimed at small scale generation (PV, wind, hydro, micro-CHP or anaerobic digestion), and the energy generated from these systems is sold back to the grid with a ‘generation tariff’ as a bonus for using these sources (DECC, 2013).

Green Deal: Aimed at households whose houses are suitable for retrofitting technology or certain micro RE such as solar panels. A loan is granted to the household by the Green Deal for a part (or all) of the cost, which is paid back at an interest rate of 7.5%/year. The calculations must work out that the repayments must not exceed the projected savings, therefore it is seen in theory as ‘no-regrets’ policy (a theory championed by the previous Australian government (Bulkeley, 2001)). The Green Deal can be combined with the FIT initiative and the energy generated can be sold back to the grid at times when it is not required.

These policies have come under much criticism due to the variation in claims of uptake, general mistrust of both the government, and more recently the energy companies themselves. The UK’s electricity and energy system is unusual, as having some of the most expensive energy in the world, and yet this electricity is still well below the entry price, which doesn't encourage investment. The Electricity Market Reform is looking to, well, reform the system to accommodate renewables, as the market depends on the balance between supply and demand, whereas renewables are seen to provide a less reliable supply, therefore unsettling the market (Helm, 2002).


Much to reiterate my previous post, this further exemplifies the need for policy consistency and a removal for political short-termism, as this will encourage greater uptake and investment in renewables in the UK. I think this is why supra-national agreements are required, because then the legislation is less easily changed with the changing of national parliament if there is an overarching policy which the country, not the government, has agreed to.

Wednesday 11 December 2013

Houses: smarter than the policy?

Following on from last week’s post focusing on community renewables, I have down-scaled again and considered renewables and sustainability at the building/home level. This also follows on from the controversy surrounding the effectiveness of the UK’s Green Deal policy which aims to effectively provide loans for energy efficiency measures such as insulation or solar panels. The number of households partaking in this scheme is vastly disputed between orders of magnitude, ranging from hundreds to hundreds of thousands. Therefore I came to wonder about and consider the feasibility of the government aim to achieve carbon zero homes to all new builds by 2016. There is vast agreement within the building community that this aim will not be achieved as the institutional framework and supply chain innovations just aren’t in place to make the extra investments worthwhile (Osmani and O’Reilly, 2009). However, if this was somehow achieved by 2016, this would go a long way to contribute to the UK’s climate change mitigation strategy and specifically help towards achieving the ambitious 80% emissions cut targeted for 2050. Currently, housing and building heating and running accounts for approx. 27% of the UK’s emissions, therefore if these buildings became self-sufficient, this would clearly be a substantial overall reduction, and therefore have significant positive ramifications for the environment and the UK’s position in global climate politics.

There are three concepts associated with sustainable housing (Seyfang, 2010):
1) High tech method – including innovations such as ‘smart houses’, using modern construction methods which monitor and adjust energy needs in the home.

2) Low tech method – off grid dwellings – utilising materials such as recycled resources and waste.

3)Shared neighbourhood facilities – such as laundry rooms and gardens, this cuts resource use and improves social capital.

The first method, the high tech route is most widely applied so far as this also includes retrofitting which has been the most common method to improve house sustainability. However, even these techniques which are so often referred to in political dialogue (especially through the Green Deal) as having successful uptake rates, are only being applied by ‘green’ building companies and not being accepted by everyday building contractors as they are seen as too risky and uncertain to justify the initial upfront costs (Seyfang,2010).

The aim of zero carbon homes by 2016 was set in 2006 along with the Code for Sustainable Homes which aims to increase regulations and requirements incrementally up to 2050. This works by awarding a level rating to houses which achieve certain thresholds in 9 categories (Communities and Local Gov., 2006):
1) Energy and CO2

2) Water

3) Materials

4) Surface water run-off

5) Waste

6) Pollution

7) Health and well-being

8) Management

9) Ecology

The house/building is rated through a points system per category and if it meets or exceeds the requirements then it is awarded a ‘level’, between 1 – 6 depending on the standard of sustainability measures. For example, for a level 4 code rating, emissions must be at least 44% lower than building regulations standard (McManus et al., 2010).

I believe that in theory this code could be effective if the drivers behind the initiative were stronger, therefore ensuing confidence in the technology which would encourage construction companies to invest in building more sustainable homes. This broadens out to the larger concept of the need for a secure and confidence-building nationwide energy policy which doesn’t change on a whim and has long term aims to encourage longer term thinking and investment.

The drivers currently, are:
1) BUSINESS: the notion of corporate social responsibility is significant as construction companies are some of the largest businesses in the UK and when the 20 largest companies were surveyed, 65% of them had a corporate sustainability policy in place.

2) CULTURAL: increasing desire among the general population to lead more sustainable lives, customer demand could help shift the type of supply.

3) LEGISLATION: the main driver currently, through the Code for Sustainable Homes.

However, the barriers to the implementation of the code are currently too high to prevent widespread action. These barriers are threefold. Firstly, technical and design barriers, mainly regarding small scale renewable energy which is perceived as unreliable. Secondly, the cultural barrier of unwillingness to implement more experimental designs to include and integrate renewable energy. And thirdly, the perceived increased costs of this implementation and the costs of ultimately breaking the economic viability barrier of this technology (Osmani and O’Reilly, 2009).

Despite these barriers I believe that the legislation is sound, and is suitably long term (up to 2050) to provide sufficient impetus to the construction industry to implement self-sustaining homes. However, my criticism would be that there is insufficient economic incentives from government and a good way to initiate this would be to incorporate RE into social housing to show how the industry can have confidence in the technology. But fundamentally, the UK needs a comprehensive and unchanging energy policy to provide confidence in the requirements of climate change mitigation and energy security in the long term, irrespective of political ideals. This will give the holistic basis to ensure the innovations required to remove the economic and cultural barriers currently associated with sustainable and zero-carbon homes.

Monday 2 December 2013

Love thy neighbour?

In light of the green tax reductions announced this week, indicating a pressure to move to a more regulated energy market, I was considering the influence that the ‘Big 6’ hold over the country, and what would happen if the market was decentralised. The notion of ‘community energy’ (CE) has been present in energy policy since around 2003 (with the Energy White Paper) although whether this has translated into an incentive for community energy projects or investment.

Community energy comes in various forms between the following three degrees of community involvement (Devine-Wright, 2005):
  •  Information led – passive recipients
  • Varying balances of partnership – between different stakeholders
  • Ownership led – high local control

And is essentially a community coming together, either independently or working with private investors and/or public sectors to construct and operationalise RE on a small scale, to either use for community energy (usually schools or village halls etc) or to be sold back to the grid to reduce energy bills.

Other European countries, especially Denmark and Germany have a much higher community energy involvement than the UK. The ideas behind CE stem from issues in the 70s regarding local energy generation (Walker and Devine-Wright, 2008) advocating the ‘soft energy path’. In the 90s, there was a (marginal) ‘dash for wind’ which led to intense opposition to renewables by local communities, the CE occurred in response to this information deficit and perceived ideas (Walker et al., 2007).

Communities can have involvement in RE projects in many ways:
  • Supporting the project and being well informed
  • Allowing the project to go ahead (not oppose it at planning stage)
  • Initiating the project through a group in the community finding investors
  • Investing financially as a community
  • Providing the manual construction for the infrastructure
  • Administering and running the operations

However, the term ‘community’ is ambiguous as there can be communities of proximity and communities of interest (Walker, 2008). Also the parameters of community are hard to define, both socially and spatially therefore flexibility in policy is required, else the meaning of community is too constrained. Caution is required when approaching a project under the term ‘community’, as labelling it as such yet not fulfilling the perceived benefits may only increase resentment towards RE energy projects on a local scale.

In the UK, in 2001, the Community Renewables Initiative set up Local Support Teams in certain areas, and these teams had significant effects; such as more than double the applications to the Clear Skies initiative (a scheme to encourage communal/community renewable) compared to areas without the Local Support Teams (Walker and Devine-Wright, 2008). However, the Community Renewables Initiative – in its 5 year lifetime – only created 150 community projects, therefore its success is very questionable and if community energy is to be encouraged, better incentives and initiatives need to be conceived.

The benefits of community energy are shown by the example of Zschadraβ in south-east Germany where the community co-owned a local wind farm and fully owned a PV cell system, through a community club. The community energy concept was created there to deal with public spending – as energy was the second biggest expense. The school’s old oil burner was replaced with a 300MW woodchip burner which heats the school, gym, club house, bowling alley and administrative buildings, and the fuel is supplied by the residents. This community is estimated to become energy independent by 2050, and all the savings from reduced energy demand, increased efficiencies and on site renewables are passed on to the community (Musall and Kuik, 2011).

Criticisms of community energy include the assumption that all in the community will want to or be able to invest time or money into the project, whereas the reality may be that only the wealthier households could participate, therefore negating the community benefits. The project may attract only those who are already heavily involved in the community or those wishing to be involved in democratic debating (Hoffman and High-Pippert, 2005).


The increased levels of acceptance of RE associated with community energy does not necessarily translate to an increased support of large scale projects, however the potential for CE is large therefore this could propose a paradigm shift in the attitudes of renewable energy. The benefits associated with this system when run and organised correctly, and to suit each different community, would be desirable to all; increased cohesion, increased sustainability, lower energy bills, reliable supply and stronger engagement with local issues.

Here is a short video from last year, from the Community Energy Roundtable, it gives a few ideas of the benefits and challenges to the future of community energy.


Friday 22 November 2013

We saw war in Warsaw (now say that 5 times fast)

Continuing along my theme of topical issues to address, this post concerns certain issues addressed and due to be addressed in Warsaw, at the COP19 talks. On the final day of these talks, there has been much controversy over the lack of productive debate over the past couple of weeks. There was also controversy over the allocation of two days of the conference, solely dedicated to the coal industry, which is still and set to continue to be the dominant energy source in Poland (Harvey, 2013). The aim of the previous week of talks with the higher echelons of governments, was to forge an agreement to be signed in Paris in 2015 and to come into force in 2020. There was the intention of having a focus and inclusion of developing countries into the agreements in this round of discussions, and they wanted clearer commitments to access to enabling funding, to the tune of $100 bn by 2020. This has been broadly agreed upon thus far, but no details confirmed, as the developed countries are keeping things vague; not overly surprising.

This follows the interesting narrative which was addressed in Warsaw; the notion of ‘loss and damage’, which was pushed by the states which are predicted to be more affected by the effects of climate change than others. This is pushed by these states because they are seen to contribute the least to the cause of climate change yet will be worst affected, therefore they want compensation or action to mitigate for climate change. Loss or damage is incurred when costs of adaptation are not recuperated, or when attempts to adapt are ineffective. Loss and damage will still occur now regardless of adaptive action or mitigating change (Huq et al., 2013). This idea was first proposed in 1991 by the small island state of Vanuatu, estimated to be eventually overtaken by sea level rise. The progress which was made in the dying hours of the conference, achieved an agreement from the ‘developed’ countries to create a compensation scheme, but no figures or mechanisms were set out. The idea of an independent body to monitor this process was unsuccessful, as the developed economies felt there shouldn’t be an automated compensation system following a crisis. (http://rt.com/news/climate-change-walkout-warsaw-050/). 

I agree with this, there shouldn’t be an automated system, and I’m not sure I even agree with the ‘loss and damage’ system as a whole. I think a far more sustainable way to prevent loss and damage is to mitigate, not adapt. Although adaptation is a key factor of living with and protecting against climate change, and help should be given to those states who are less economically able to provide sufficient adaptive measures or in worst case scenario; emergency aid. I believe that the developed countries should be helping where they can, but a far more constructive method would be instead of giving lump sums of money, to subsidize renewable energy technology for them or promote community renewables, while working to reduce domestic energy use and greenhouse emissions. This two tier approach would allow economic growth in the developing regions, enabling them to help themselves through climate change mitigation and adaptation. Also, the developed countries, who are (historically, at least) far more guilty in the trial of who emitted the most CO2, would be working towards a lower carbon economy, no longer with the excuse of waiting for the developing economies.

The role of renewables in the shift to a lower carbon economy is widely accepted as critical. Although, the exact relationship between the expansion of RE and climate change trends are very hard to determine due to the vast numbers of variables, and the varying role of the carbon cycle (Krey and Clarke, 2011). Two key problems which arise when trying to create RE targets (especially in an international setting) are:
  1. Strategic planning takes place under high uncertainty
  2. Decision makers should be planning for large increases in RE – and this is difficult to plan on a large scale.

The expansion rate of RE is indicative of the support provided to the technology (both public and private support). It is thought that some renewables are more influenced by public support (through policy) than others; for instance, solar and geothermal are seen to be more influenced, as those technologies are less developed than wind or hydropower (Kray andClarke, 2011).

Looking to the future, as the talks in Warsaw attempted to do, indicates that much higher investment costs will be required to extract and transport conventional fuels, therefore creating a natural economic shift to alternatives. However, by this point, the emissions could be too high and stabilisation might not occur till 650ppm. Therefore CO2 can be reduced through increased conversion efficiencies of heat and electricity plants, increased efficiencies of end of pipe solutions, improved energy management systems and carbon sequestration (Sims, 2001). Therefore RE may well not be the silver bullet we were all hoping for, but it may come to be the trusty broad sword.